Product Code Database
Example Keywords: coat -undershirt $1
barcode-scavenger
   » » Wiki: Vector Measure
Tag Wiki 'Vector Measure'.
Tag

In , a vector measure is a function defined on a family of sets and taking values satisfying certain properties. It is a generalization of the concept of finite measure, which takes values only.


Definitions and first consequences
Given a field of sets (\Omega, \mathcal F) and a X, a finitely additive vector measure (or measure, for short) is a function \mu:\mathcal {F} \to X such that for any two A and B in \mathcal{F} one has \mu(A\cup B) =\mu(A) + \mu (B).

A vector measure \mu is called countably additive if for any (A_i)_{i=1}^{\infty} of disjoint sets in \mathcal F such that their union is in \mathcal F it holds that \mu{\left(\bigcup_{i=1}^\infty A_i\right)} = \sum_{i=1}^{\infty}\mu(A_i) with the series on the right-hand side convergent in the norm of the Banach space X.

It can be proved that an additive vector measure \mu is countably additive if and only if for any sequence (A_i)_{i=1}^{\infty} as above one has

where \|\cdot\| is the norm on X.

Countably additive vector measures defined on are more general than finite measures, finite , and , which are countably additive functions taking values respectively on the real interval [0, \infty), the set of , and the set of .


Examples
Consider the field of sets made up of the interval 0, together with the family \mathcal F of all Lebesgue measurable sets contained in this interval. For any such set A, define \mu(A) = \chi_A where \chi is the indicator function of A. Depending on where \mu is declared to take values, two different outcomes are observed.

  • \mu, viewed as a function from \mathcal F to the L^\infty(0,), is a vector measure which is not countably-additive.
  • \mu, viewed as a function from \mathcal F to the L^p-space L^1(0,), is a countably-additive vector measure.

Both of these statements follow quite easily from the criterion () stated above.


The variation of a vector measure
Given a vector measure \mu : \mathcal{F} \to X, the variation |\mu| of \mu is defined as |\mu|(A)=\sup \sum_{i=1}^n \|\mu(A_i)\| where the is taken over all the partitions A = \bigcup_{i=1}^n A_i of A into a finite number of disjoint sets, for all A in \mathcal{F}. Here, \|\cdot\| is the norm on X.

The variation of \mu is a finitely additive function taking values in 0,. It holds that \|\mu(A)\| \leq |\mu|(A) for any A in \mathcal{F}. If |\mu|(\Omega) is finite, the measure \mu is said to be of bounded variation. One can prove that if \mu is a vector measure of bounded variation, then \mu is countably additive if and only if |\mu| is countably additive.


Lyapunov's theorem
In the theory of vector measures, * states that the range of a (non-atomic) finite-dimensional vector measure is and .Kluvánek, I., Knowles, G., Vector Measures and Control Systems, North-Holland Mathematics Studies  20, Amsterdam, 1976.
(1977). 9780821815151, American Mathematical Society.
(1987). 9789027721860, D. Reidel Publishing Co.; PWN—Polish Scientific Publishers.
In fact, the range of a non-atomic vector measure is a (the closed and convex set that is the limit of a convergent sequence of ). It is used in economics, This paper builds on two papers by Aumann:

Vind's article was noted by with this comment:
The concept of a convex set (i.e., a set containing the segment connecting any two of its points) had repeatedly been placed at the center of economic theory before 1964. It appeared in a new light with the introduction of integration theory in the study of economic competition: If one associates with every agent of an economy an arbitrary set in the commodity space and if one averages those individual sets over a collection of insignificant agents, then the resulting set is necessarily convex. Debreu But explanations of the ... functions of prices ... can be made to rest on the convexity of sets derived by that averaging process. Convexity in the commodity space obtained by aggregation over a collection of insignificant agents is an insight that economic theory owes ... to integration theory. ''Italics

in ("bang–bang") , and in statistical theory. Lyapunov's theorem has been proved by using the Shapley–Folkman lemma, which has been viewed as a analogue of Lyapunov's theorem.

(2025). 9780333786765, Palgrave Macmillan. .
Page 210:


See also

Bibliography
  • (1997). 9783764330033, Birkhäuser Verlag. .
  • (1977). 9780821815151, American Mathematical Society.
  • Kluvánek, I., Knowles, G, Vector Measures and Control Systems, North-Holland Mathematics Studies  20, Amsterdam, 1976.
  • (1973). 9780070542259, McGraw-Hill. .

Page 1 of 1
1
Page 1 of 1
1

Account

Social:
Pages:  ..   .. 
Items:  .. 

Navigation

General: Atom Feed Atom Feed  .. 
Help:  ..   .. 
Category:  ..   .. 
Media:  ..   .. 
Posts:  ..   ..   .. 

Statistics

Page:  .. 
Summary:  .. 
1 Tags
10/10 Page Rank
5 Page Refs